Distributional Effects of Raising the Social Security Taxable Maximum

by
Policy Brief No. 2009-01 (released July 2009)

Related Content

Fact Sheet: Taxable Maximum Earners

Policy Option Projections: Taxation Changes

As of 2009, Social Security's Old-Age, Survivors, and Disability Insurance program limits the amount of annual earnings subject to taxation at $106,800, and this value generally increases annually based on changes in the national average wage index. This brief uses Modeling Income in the Near Term (MINT) projections to compare the distributional effects of four options for raising the maximum taxable earnings amount beyond its scheduled levels. Two of the options would raise this value so that it covers 90 percent of all covered earnings and two would remove the maximum completely. Within each set of options, the proposals are differentiated by whether the new taxable amounts are used in computing benefits. Most workers would not be affected by these proposals, but some higher earners would experience a substantial increase in taxes. Correspondingly, benefit increases are largely isolated to higher earners, although the return in benefits for taxes paid would also decline. Because the proposals are targeted toward high earners, Social Security's progressivity would increase.


Kevin Whitman is with the Social Security Administration's (SSA's) Office of Retirement and Disability Policy. Questions about this analysis should be directed to the author at (202) 358-6317.

Acknowledgments: The author thanks Laura Haltzel, Kathleen Romig, Joyce Manchester, Mark Sarney, David Weaver, Jason Fichtner, and Dave Shoffner for their helpful comments and suggestions.

The findings and conclusions presented in this brief are those of the author and do not necessarily represent the views of the Social Security Administration.

The original version of this brief contained an error in Chart 1. The two lines were inversely identified. The corrected line labels now appear in this brief. [Posted: March 21, 2017.]

Summary

Selected Abbreviations
MINT Modeling Income in the Near Term
OASDI Old-Age, Survivors, and Disability Insurance
OCACT Office of the Chief Actuary
tax max taxable maximum

This policy brief analyzes the effects on taxpayers and Social Security beneficiaries of either eliminating the taxable maximum (tax max) for Social Security or raising it to a level so that 90 percent of all Old-Age, Survivors, and Disability Insurance (OASDI)–covered earnings would be subject to the payroll tax. Under both scenarios it is possible to either calculate benefits based on the current-law tax max (no max and max 90) or to credit the new taxable amounts toward benefits (no max plus benefits and max 90 plus benefits).1

The distributional results presented herein are from the Modeling Income in the Near Term (MINT) microsimulation model.2 The four options are assumed to take effect in 2008, consistent with the latest start date used by Social Security's Office of the Chief Actuary (OCACT) in its solvency projections for these options using the 2005 Trustees Report. The results focus on those aged 62 or older in 2070 to determine the effects of these changes on individuals spending most or all of their working careers under the policy options discussed here. The outcomes associated with each of the policy options are compared with current law. In addition, the immediate tax rate increase required to completely close the 75-year solvency gap (1.92 percentage points) is used as a reference point for comparing these options with a solvent baseline.3 The major findings are as follows:

The Current Taxable Maximum Covers Roughly 84 Percent of Total Earnings

Beginning in 1975, the amount of earnings subject to Social Security taxes was indexed to the change in the national average wage index.7 Congress passed the last major financing amendments for the system in 1983, and at that time Social Security covered 90 percent of taxable wages. However, wages above the tax max have grown at a faster rate than wages subject to the payroll tax. As a result, the ratio of taxable wages to covered wages has declined from 90 percent in 1983 to 83.6 percent in 2006 despite the automatic increase in the wage base.8, 9 At an individual rather than economy-wide level, roughly 6 percent of covered workers had earnings above the tax max as of 2005.

As established by the 1983 Amendments to the Social Security Act, the Social Security payroll tax rate applied to these wages is a combined 12.4 percent, with 6.2 percent paid by the employee and 6.2 percent paid by the employer.10 In 2009, a worker earning $106,800 or more would pay $6,621.60 in payroll taxes to the Social Security (or OASDI) program, with the individual's employer also paying the same amount.11, 12

For benefit purposes, an employee's earnings for a year are also capped at the tax max. As many as 35 years of the highest earnings are used to calculate OASDI benefits, and only earnings up to the tax max in those years are figured into the benefit computation. Allowing higher earnings to be included in the benefit formula would increase benefits.

The No Max and Max 90 Options Would Change the Current-Law Taxable Maximum Starting in 2008

The no max and no max plus benefits options completely remove the upper limit on the wage base that is subject to the payroll tax starting in 2008. The max 90 and max 90 plus benefits options gradually increase the tax max beginning in 2008 so that by 2017, 90 percent of all OASDI-covered earnings would be subject to the payroll tax. From 2018 onward, the annual tax max would equal the previous year's tax max multiplied by 1 plus the percentage growth in the average wage index. Chart 1 shows the tax max under current law and the max 90 and max 90 plus benefits options (combined under the heading "Max 90 options").13 The gap between the current-law tax max and the proposed max 90 and max 90 plus benefits options reaches $155,412 by 2017.

Chart 1.
The tax-max value under current law and the proposed max 90 options, 2008–2017
Line chart with tabular version below.
Show as table
Table equivalent for Chart 1. The tax-max value under current law and the proposed max 90 options, 2008–2017
Year Current law Max 90 options
2008 100,160 108,300
2009 104,107 121,500
2010 108,387 136,200
2011 112,747 152,400
2012 117,267 170,400
2013 121,919 190,500
2014 126,795 213,300
2015 131,714 238,500
2016 136,851 267,000
2017 142,188 297,600
 
SOURCE: Results are from SSA's MINT model.
a. Max 90 and max 90 plus benefits options are combined here.

All of the Options Would Improve Solvency, but Not to the Same Degree

When comparing all of these policy options it is important to emphasize that they do not improve solvency equally. Using the assumptions in the 2005 Trustees Report, the no max option is the only option projected to fully close the long-range actuarial imbalance; the no max plus benefits, max 90, and max 90 plus benefits options address smaller parts of the long-range shortfall (Table 1).14 None of these options are sustainably solvent, meaning that Social Security is paying more in benefits than it is receiving in taxes at the end of the projection period, and the OASDI Trust Fund ratio is declining.15

Table 1. Effect of increasing or removing the tax max on solvency, by policy option
Effect No max No max plus benefits Max 90 Max 90 plus benefits
Change in actuarial balance as percentage of taxable payroll 2.21 1.82 1.00 0.83
Percentage of long-range actuarial imbalance fixed 114.58 94.79 51.56 43.23
Percentage of annual shortfall fixed in the 75th year 50.70 36.14 25.79 16.84
SOURCE: Based on calculations by OCACT, SSA, http://www.socialsecurity.gov/OACT/solvency/provisions_tr2005/wagebase.html.

The Majority of Individuals Aged 62 or Older in 2070 Would Not be Affected by These Options

Because these policy changes only affect those persons who ever have wages exceeding the current-law tax max, the majority of individuals are not affected by the change. Roughly 77 percent of persons aged 62 or older in 2070 are projected to never have sufficient annual earnings to exceed the current-law tax max amount in the years following the implementation date of these policy options (Chart 2); this means that under all of the policy options discussed here, only 23 percent of individuals would experience an increase in payroll taxes paid during their lifetime. However, for the no max plus benefits and max 90 plus benefits options, a larger percentage of individuals would be affected in some way, not because of an increased individual tax burden, but as a result of receiving higher benefits from the earnings record for a worker who exceeded the tax max (that is, being the recipient of auxiliary benefits). Measuring the overall affected population as defined by those with a change in their net present value of benefits greater than a dollar, 38 percent of individuals would be affected by the no max plus benefits and the max 90 plus benefits options, with 40 percent of this affected group receiving increased benefits without a change in their individual taxes paid.

Chart 2.
Persons aged 62 or older in 2070 exceeding the scheduled tax max, by number of years (starting in 2008) their earnings exceed the tax max (in percent)
Bar chart with tabular version below.
Show as table
Table equivalent for Chart 2. Persons aged 62 or older in 2070 exceeding the scheduled tax max, by number of years (starting in 2008) their earnings exceed the tax max (in percent)
Number of years over the tax max Percent of persons earning above the tax max
Never 76.94
1 4.05
2–5 6.02
6–10 3.86
11–15 1.76
16–20 2.43
21–25 1.83
26–30 1.35
31 or more 1.76
 
SOURCE: Results are for persons aged 62 or older in 2070, using SSA's MINT model.

Individuals in Higher-Earning Households Would Pay More in Taxes Compared with Current Law

Although most individuals would not experience a change in their tax burden, the highest lifetime earners would, on average, see their taxes increase under each of the options compared with current law. Among individuals aged 62 or older in 2070 in the top 25th percentile for shared lifetime earnings, the median equivalent tax increase on lifetime earnings would be 0.15 percentage points for all of the options (Chart 3).16 The higher the shared-earnings percentile, the higher the equivalent tax increase. For those in the highest 10th percentile for shared lifetime earnings, the median equivalent tax increase would be 1.92 percentage points for the no max and no max plus benefits options and 1.91 percentage points for the max 90 and max 90 plus benefits options.

Chart 3.
Taxes on higher lifetime earners increase, on average, under all policy options compared with current law
Bar chart with tabular version below.
Show as table
Table equivalent for Chart 3. Taxes on higher lifetime earners increase, on average, under all policy options compared with current law
Policy option set Lifetime shared-earnings percentile
Top 25% Top 10% Top 5%
No Max 0.15 1.92 5.84
Max 90 0.15 1.91 5.00
 
SOURCE: Results are for persons aged 62 or older in 2070, using SSA's MINT model.
NOTE: No max and no max plus benefits options are combined here. Max 90 and max 90 plus benefits options are combined here.

The equivalent tax increase is calculated by taking the difference between the present value of payroll tax paid under the option and current law and dividing this amount by the present value of taxable covered earnings under current law. This value represents the immediate tax increase that would be equal to the overall change in an individual's tax burden occurring under the policy option (that is, a 2.0 percentage-point increase is the equivalent of the combined employer and employee OASDI payroll tax rate increasing from 12.4 percent under current law, to 14.4 percent under the option).

As a comparison, using the 2005 Trustees Report, which corresponds with the solvency estimates included in this brief, OCACT estimates that completely fixing the program's shortfall over the 75-year projection period would require an immediate across-the-board tax increase of 1.92 percentage points. Note that although the median percentage-point equivalent tax increases for even the top 10 percent of lifetime earners under all four of the options are roughly equivalent to the 1.92 percentage-point tax rate increase needed to close the 75-year solvency gap, some individuals would experience a significantly higher equivalent tax increase. For example, under the no max and no max plus benefits options, the median equivalent tax increase among those in the top 5 percent of lifetime shared-earners is 5.84 percentage points. For the max 90 and max 90 plus benefits options, the comparable figure is 5.00 percentage points. These findings underscore the distributional trade-offs between a general tax increase and changes to the tax max that are specifically targeted toward higher earners.

Among Individuals in Higher-Earning Households, Benefit Levels Would Increase on Average under the No Max Plus Benefits and Max 90 Plus Benefits Options

The no max plus benefits and the max 90 plus benefits options would both increase benefits because the new taxable amounts also would be credited for benefit calculations (Table 2). Under the no max plus benefits option, the median percentage change in annual benefits for individuals aged 62 or older in 2070 in the highest shared-earnings quintile is projected to be 7.5 percent. For the max 90 plus benefits option, the comparable benefit increase for the same group is projected to be 6.3 percent. Benefit increases would be concentrated among households representing the highest fifth of earners because individuals in this group would have a higher number of years with wages above the current-law tax max.

Table 2. Benefit increases are concentrated among persons in higher-earning households, by selected policy option
Lifetime shared-earnings quintile Median percentage change in annual benefits
No max plus benefits Max 90 plus benefits
Lowest quintile 0.0 0.0
Second lowest quintile 0.0 0.0
Middle quintile 0.0 0.0
Second highest quintile 0.0 0.0
Highest quintile 7.5 6.3
SOURCE: Results are for persons aged 62 or older in 2070, using SSA's MINT model.
NOTE: Annual benefits under the immediate 1.92 percent tax increase needed to close the 75-year solvency shortfall would be the same as under current law.

The Return in Benefits for Taxes Paid Would Also Decline for Individuals in Higher-Earning Households

The effect of increased taxes and benefits would also be seen in the benefit/tax ratio, which measures the amount that workers receive from the program for every dollar of taxes paid. In 2070, among individuals aged 62 or older in the highest shared-earnings quintile, the benefit/tax ratio would markedly decrease under all of the options, except for the max 90 plus benefits option (Table 3).17 The average decline would be roughly the same under the no max, no max plus benefits, and max 90 options, with the median benefit/tax ratio for the highest shared-earnings quintile falling from 0.9 under current law to 0.8.18 In addition, under the no max option, the median benefit/tax ratio for individuals aged 62 or older in the second highest shared-earnings quintile would also decline. In many instances, the benefit/tax ratio value would still be higher than the median benefit/tax ratio for the same earnings group under the proposal to immediately increase the tax rate by 1.92 percentage points. However, because all four of the options are so narrowly targeted, there are individuals who would experience a far larger decrease in their benefit/tax ratio than under the immediate tax increase option.

Table 3. Money's worth declines most for persons in higher-earning households, by policy option
Lifetime shared-earnings quintile Median benefit/tax ratio
Current law 1.92 percentage-point tax rate increase No max No max plus benefits Max 90 Max 90 plus benefits
Lowest quintile 1.9 1.7 1.9 1.9 1.9 1.9
Second lowest quintile 1.4 1.2 1.4 1.4 1.4 1.4
Middle quintile 1.1 1.0 1.1 1.1 1.1 1.1
Second highest quintile 1.1 0.9 1.0 1.1 1.1 1.1
Highest quintile 0.9 0.8 0.8 0.8 0.8 0.9
SOURCE: Results are for persons aged 62 or older in 2070, using SSA's MINT model.

Increasing or Eliminating the Taxable Maximum Would Make Social Security More Progressive

By increasing taxes on individuals with Social Security–covered wages in excess of the current-law tax max, the Social Security system's progressivity would increase. Progressivity can be measured by an index that ranges from 0 (benefits are exactly proportional to lifetime taxes paid) to 1 (highest earners bear the entire tax burden, and lower earners receive all of the benefits).19, 20 Chart 4 shows that the progressivity value for the affected birth cohorts is generally between 0.15 and 0.17 under current law, but would increase under all of the options.21 The no max and max 90 options have the highest progressivity values because they increase payroll taxes on high earners without crediting this amount toward benefits.

Chart 4.
Most progressive policy option: No max
Line chart with tabular version below.
Show as table
Table equivalent for Chart 4. Most progressive policy option: No max
5-year birth cohort Progressivity index value
Current law Tax rate increase No Max No Max Plus Benefits Max 90 Max 90 Plus Benefits
1930 0.26 0.26 0.26 0.26 0.26 0.26
1935 0.21 0.21 0.21 0.21 0.21 0.21
1940 0.18 0.18 0.18 0.18 0.18 0.18
1945 0.18 0.18 0.18 0.18 0.18 0.18
1950 0.15 0.15 0.16 0.15 0.15 0.15
1955 0.15 0.15 0.16 0.15 0.15 0.15
1960 0.15 0.15 0.17 0.15 0.16 0.15
1965 0.15 0.15 0.19 0.16 0.16 0.15
1970 0.15 0.15 0.20 0.16 0.17 0.15
1975 0.15 0.15 0.25 0.20 0.18 0.16
1980 0.16 0.17 0.24 0.18 0.20 0.17
1985 0.18 0.19 0.27 0.21 0.22 0.20
1990 0.17 0.17 0.25 0.19 0.21 0.18
1995 0.17 0.17 0.23 0.18 0.21 0.18
2000 0.17 0.17 0.26 0.20 0.21 0.18
2005 0.17 0.17 0.27 0.20 0.21 0.18
2010 0.17 0.17 0.24 0.19 0.21 0.18
 
SOURCE: Results are from SSA's MINT model.
NOTE: The label for 1930 includes persons born from 1926 to 1930.
The line in this chart representing current-law progressivity is largely obscured by the line showing progressivity under the tax rate increase option because the underlying values are nearly identical.

Notes

1 To make it easier to identify these policy options when they are cited in the text of this brief, their titles will continue to be noted in italics.

2 Readers interested in detail on MINT should see "Modeling Income in the Near Term 4" by Smith, Cashin, and Favreault (2005), available at http://www.urban.org/UploadedPDF/411191_MINT4.pdf.

3 A solvent baseline is used because according to the most recent estimates from the 2008 Trustees Report, OCACT projects that Social Security will lack the funds necessary to pay current-law benefits starting in 2041.

4 This solvency estimate corresponds with projections from OCACT based on the 2005 Trustees Report. The figures based on the 2005 Report are used because they are the solvency estimates closest to the 2004 assumptions used in MINT. OCACT has produced new estimates using the 2008 Trustees Report, but the changes in the program's projected actuarial balance are minor. OCACT periodically updates their solvency scores and readers interested in the most recent estimates should see http://www.socialsecurity.gov/OACT/solvency/provisions/wagebase.html.

5 The median benefit/tax ratio for those in the highest lifetime shared-earnings quintile would also decrease under the max 90 plus benefits option, but the decline would not be large enough to change the rounded values.

6 Although the two analyses use several different measures, as well as a different analysis year, these results are qualitatively similar to those produced by the Congressional Research Service using the Dynasim model. Available at http://www.aging.senate.gov/crs/ss7.pdf.

7 Prior to the implementation of changes mandated by the 1972 Amendments to the Social Security Act, Congress raised the tax max intermittently on an ad hoc basis.

8 The ratio of taxable wages to covered wages in 2006 is preliminary and reported in the Annual Statistical Supplement to the Social Security Bulletin, 2007 (Table 4.B1). See http://www.socialsecurity.gov/policy/docs/statcomps/supplement/2007/4b.pdf.

9 Prior to 1994, self-employment earnings above the annual tax max were not reported to Social Security, resulting in the ratio of taxable wages to covered wages being overstated. Adjusting for this change in the calculation methodology would mean that the dollar targets for the tax max under the max 90 and max 90 plus benefits options would need to be lowered to match the ratio as of the 1983 Amendments. This adjustment is not included in this analysis, as the phase-in figures for the tax max 90 options used in the projections and Chart 1 are from OCACT. Available at http://www.ssab.gov/documents/Taxable-Ratio-Computations-092905.pdf for more information.

10 The 1983 Amendments refer to Public Law 98-21 (H.R. 1900). For a summary of the law's provisions, see http://www.socialsecurity.gov/history/1983amend.html.

11 See http:/www.socialsecurity.gov/policy/docs/chartbooks/fast_facts/2008/fast_facts08.html#generalinfo.

12 However, it is generally argued that the employee effectively bears the burden for the entire 12.4 percent Social Security payroll tax because the employer passes on the cost of their portion of the tax to the employee through lower wages. (See "A Guide to Social Security Money's Worth Issues," by Leimer (1995), available at http://www.socialsecurity.gov/policy/docs/workingpapers/wp67.pdf.) Thus, the total tax burden for a worker earning at or above the tax max in 2009 would be $13,243.20.

13 The no max and no max plus benefits options are not included in Chart 1 because starting in 2008, there is no tax max under these options.

14 OCACT's more recent modeling of these proposals projects that the no max plus benefits option will also solve the long-range solvency imbalance. Available at http://www.socialsecurity.gov/OACT/solvency/provisions/charts/chart_run214.pdf.

15 The 1.92 percentage-point tax increase used for comparison in this brief is also not sustainably solvent. The most commonly used sustainably solvent baseline is payable benefits, which represents what Social Security is projected to be able to pay without any reform. Payable benefits is not included as a baseline in this analysis because it achieves solvency solely through benefit reductions, starting in 2041 (according to the 2008 Trustees Report). The options included here focus on immediate tax changes. Consequently, it is difficult to construct a meaningful comparison.

16 To address earnings on a household level, the shared-earnings measures attributes half of a married couple's earnings to each individual during the time of their marriage.

17 There are a variety of ways to calculate the benefit/tax ratio based on how one attributes taxes and benefits. This analysis divides the lifetime benefits an individual receives, regardless of the source (that is, the benefits could be based on another person's work record, such as a spouse), by the lifetime taxes the individual paid.

18 The projected values are not exactly equal, but round to the same number.

19 Under a regressive system, the index would have a negative value.

20 For a more complete description of the progressivity index, see "A Progressivity Index for Social Security" by Biggs, Sarney, and Tamborini (2009), available at http://www.socialsecurity.gov/policy/docs/issuepapers/ip2009-01.pdf.

21 Readers may notice the zigzag pattern in the no max and max 90 progressivity lines. This variation primarily results from fluctuations in earnings patterns for the different cohorts among the small percentage of workers who earn above the current-law tax max. These changes are amplified in the progressivity values because these options do not count the increased taxable earnings for benefits.